Networks
of Influence: Stakeholder Theory, Director Networks, and the Governance of Firm
Resources
David Aldama-Navarrete (I will be taking the second module)
Introduction
and Background
In this paper, I will explore the responsiveness of firms
to the personal connections of their board directors. In doing so, I will
investigate how the firm interacts with external stakeholders, and how firm
relationships with third parties are mediated by the personal relationships of
senior management.
The firm has been traditionally seen by economists as either a “production function” or a non-market mechanism for economic exchange, in which transaction costs are curtailed through the establishment of vertical supply chains. In this view, firm management acts as a planner that chooses inputs as to optimize production and maximize profits. The question remains of who internalizes value created by companies. An implicit assumption made by the classical literature is that the firm’s managers are solely “agents” of a “principal” who wholly owns the firm’s resources. In the traditional view, this principal –the owner(s) of the firm’s equity–captures all economic value added by the company.
Reality, however, is slightly more complex. The firm
exists at the intersection of the interests of many parties with differing
motivations and incentives. The interests of these parties (consumers,
governments, consumers, host communities, etc.) are sometimes aligned, but
often not. Firms must offer all of these “stakeholders” a modicum of benefit,
lest they lose their “social license to operate”.
Stakeholder theory is a relatively new theoretical
development[1]
that seeks to make sense of the firm –insofar as the firm serves as a mechanism
for value distribution to multiple “principals”. This theory posits that that
multiple social groups –stakeholders –have “claims” on the resources and
profits of the firm. In this view, managers are, to some degree, agents of all
these groups vying for a share of the firm’s profits, and must –dynamically–allocate
these accordingly.
The
Social Networks Analysis Angle
Stakeholder groups, however, are represented by
people. Furthermore, personal networks –social, professional, and civic–provide
a conduit for the “informal contracting” by which stakeholder groups exercise
pressures on the firm. This paper will try to uncover the mechanisms by which this
informal contracting takes place.
Following Barnea and Guedj (2007)[2], I
will map director networks and generate a variety of network measures for
these. Also following these authors, the network matrix will be constructed as
follows: for each firm and each year, a mapping of connections among the different
directors in the sample will be created. Rows and columns will represent all
directors for a specific year. If director i and director j sit together on a board, the value of cell (i, j) in the matrix will be 1; otherwise
it will be 0.[3]
Hypotheses
The main hypotheses of this work are that companies are responsive to:
- The personal interests of their board members, as revealed by their participation in other boards (of for-profit or non-profit organizations).
- The interests of the personal connections of their board members, as proxied by the board memberships of these connections.
Responsiveness will be proxied by the likelihood of
approving shareholder proposals that benefit these interests. A central issue
in the analysis will be the determination of the maximal connection-path length
for which responsiveness occurs. By means of exploratory data analysis, I also
hope to derive additional hypotheses regarding the influence that director
networks have on the behavior of the firm. I am particularly interested in the
effects that tightly connected sub-groups of directors (cliques, k-cores, etc.)
might have on their firms.
Data
For the purposes of mapping director networks, I
intend to use the RiskMetrics Director database, which consists of a collection
of Board Director data for each of the companies included in the S&P1500 stock
index, from 1996 to the present.
For the purposes of determining the dependent
variables, I will use the RiskMetrics Shareholder Proposal database, as well as
the RiskMetrics Voting Results database, which tally–respectively–all
shareholder proposals for each of the companies included in the S&P 1500
stock index and all voting results for management proposals for the same set of
companies, from 1996 onward.
Potential
data limitations and issues
The RiskMetrics databases are owned by MSCI, the
market information firm. In order to access this data, an access license must
be purchased. I have contacted the MSCI sales department regarding the
possibility of purchasing a license for research purposes, but have not yet
received a reply. If I do not gain
access to the necessary databases, I will have to construct director and voting
databases from publicly available data, including shareholder reports, which
will surely draw down sample size.
[1] The
birth of stakeholder theory can be traced back to R. Edward Freeman’s seminal
work Strategic Management: A Stakeholder
Approach, published in 1984.
[2] Barnea,
Amir, and Ilan Guedj. "Director Networks and firm governance."
Unpublished working paper, University of Texas–Austin (2007).
[3] Ibid.
1 comment:
Good topic. I like your idea of linking corporate board members together through their involvement in non-profits. Never seen that. Two thoughts. First, the amount of data you're proposing to sift through is huge. You need to adopt a selection strategy that will give you results without drowning you (every 3-5 years rather than every year, perhaps?)
Board links, shareholder proposals--all good but you need to come up with a more tightly-worded Question, as again, you're biting off a lot with all this.
Post a Comment